Independent Research and Policy Advocacy

Theory of Consumer Protection II: Insights from Behavioral Economics

Save Post

In the second blog in the Consumer Financial Protection series, we explore insights from behavioral economics that could fundamentally impact the design of legislation and regulation for consumer protection in finance.

 

Neo-classical economic theories like expected utility hypothesis and efficient market hypothesis are based on the assumption that the consumer is a rational agent. However, recent insights from behavioral economics point out that the consumers do not always behave as time-consistent, rational utility maximizers. Consumers are, in fact, beset with a number of cognitive limitations and biases which influence their decision making and make them acts in ways contrary to the traditional model of hyper-rationality. We will explore some of the insights from cognitive psychology and experimental economics that could impact the design of consumer protection legislation and regulation in the future.

Prospect Theory:

The work of behavioral economists Daniel Kahneman and Amos Tversky provided early insights into consumer behavior. Their seminal work found evidence to suggest that consumers do not make decisions that expected utility theory predicts. The central insights of this theory help explain observed consumer behaviors such as:

a. Loss Aversion: People are extremely sensitive about losses and exhibit deep seated loss aversion to even small amounts of money. In fact, there is evidence that individuals are more sensitive to losses than profits – in fact, people value moderate losses more than twice as much equal sized gains (Tversky and Kahneman: 1991). This translates into financial decisions that would be at significant variance from the theory of expected utility.

b. Incorrect Probability Calculations: People have a tendency to overweigh small probabilities and under-estimate risks with larger probabilities. This explains why people more readily buy insurance on refrigerators and TV sets, but are less likely to buy life or accident coverage. Individuals also tend to be more sensitive to differences in probabilities at higher probability levels.

c. Response to Framing: People make different choices in identical situations because of the way the choices have been framed for them. The way in which a problem is described can be responsible for upto a 30-40% shift in preferences (Barberis and Thaler: 2003). The fact that framing can fundamentally impact consumer choice means that investor welfare could be seriously compromised in the absence of countervailing regulation.

d. Mental Accounting: The process people use to formulate financial problems for themselves is called mental accounting (Avgouleas: 2006). One classic case of mental accounting is “narrow framing”, where individuals evaluate a particular gamble (or financial transaction) as if it were independent of everything else in the world and not assess its utility in terms of the gamble’s effect on the individual’s overall wealth.

Biases and cognitive limitations:

Human beings also exhibit biases and other cognitive limitations that can contribute to poor decision making. In the context of financial products, consumers are prone to take decisions that can have negative future consequences for themselves (also called internalities).

a. Self-restraint: Consumers often behave in ways that compromise long-term well-being for short-term gains. This bias of present consumption out-weighing future welfare manifests itself in various forms such as the failure to save for retirement. It is also observed that consumers discount future benefits/costs in a time-inconsistent manner. For example, if offered $100 now and $200 a year from now, a consumer is likely to choose the immediate $100. However, when offered $100 five years from now and $200 six years from now, a consumer is likely to wait the additional year even though the it is the same choice she makes five years from now. This time inconsistent, present biased model of discounting is referred to as hyperbolic discounting.

b. Herding: Consumers often mimic behavioral patterns of peer leaders or peer groups, leading them to ignore signs and indicators that would lead a rational consumer to take different decisions. Such irrational behavior is fueled by overconfidence (in peer leaders or rating agencies and in assessments of new financial products) and can often threaten systemic stability. History is replete with examples of irrational behavior leading to economic bubbles, from the Tulip mania in the 1600s to the present financial crisis caused partly by the real estate bubble in the USA.

c. Information Overload: In the previous blog post, we mentioned Akerlof’s seminal study of the used-car industry, where information asymmetry leads to market inefficiency. Contrary to expectations, a regulatory response to provide the consumer with additional information (beyond a point) can be counterproductive. This happens due to the phenomenon of information overload, where the consumer is unable to assess the quality and amount of information given to them. Examples of this phenomenon include consumers casually flicking through tens of pages of terms and conditions when insurance is bought online, without understanding the risks and clauses involved.

Systemic irrationality and regulatory responses:

There are several limitations to the use of insights from behavioral economics in consumer financial protection.

Work in experimental economics argues for the emergence of rational behavior in the context of a repetitive market activity. Consumers display rational behavior in the long run, through a trial and error adaptation process and repeated market activity and spurts of irrationality are characteristic only of the short run. So, consumer irrationality, it is argued, can only be a factor in the policy of consumer protection, not the starting point. Second, behavioral economics is yet to come up with an all-encompassing theory of the market or consumer choice that can challenge the existing neo-classical theories; it has only pointed out deficiencies of the latter. Third, behavioral economics does not formulate any normative principles, which can be used either for empirical testing as economic models or for normative use as a guideline to an efficient market mechanism.

Even if consumer irrationality is an exception to the norm of rational behavior, the insights of behavioral economics alert us to the possible risks of systemic irrational behavior and the consequence this can have on the financial system. Any regulatory mechanism should therefore be designed to be able to respond to systemic irrationality. However, regulators should be required to tread carefully before intervening in a situation of perceived systemic irrationality. At the very least they must have to demonstrate indications of irrationality in the system, provide plausible explanations of how such irrationality can have a financial system-wide impact and finally make clear the case for how their proposed regulation will be effective in countering the irrational behavior.

To ‘nudge’ or not to ‘nudge’?

If consumers cannot maximize their own welfare (due to lack of cognitive capability or financial literacy), it is argued that regulation needs to ‘nudge’ the consumers into making those decisions which reflect the presumed judgment of what consumers would want, were they fully informed or well advised. This approach is referred to as libertarian or asymmetric paternalism.

The idea behind libertarian or asymmetric paternalism is not to restrict the consumer’s autonomy; rather it seeks to counter the harmful effects of cognitive biases without affecting the choices of the less behaviorally challenged consumers. Some of the suggested regulations include increased pluralism in information disclosure formats and in the prescribed volume of information reaching different investor classes, mandated use of structured and edited investment contracts that consumers can easily comprehend and mandatory use of long term performance reports. These suggestions imply that regulators must drop the ‘one size fits all’ approach as consumers’ decisions vary depending on factors such as income, education, age, attitude and the type of financial product they consume.

There are, however, strong arguments against the ‘nudge’ principle on the grounds of its interventionist approach, implied restrictions of choice and possible impact on rational consumers. These arguments speak to the heart of debates around behavioral economics and consumer protection today.

References
1. Backstrom, Hans. Financial consumer protection- goals, opportunities and problems. Economic Review. 2010
2. Campbell, John Y., Jackson E Howell et al. Consumer Financial Protection. Volume 25, Number 1. Pp 91-114. Journal of Economic Perspectives. 2011
3. Spindler, Gerald. Behavioral Finance and Investor Protection Regulations. Journal of Consumer Policy. 2011
4. Emilios, Avgouleas. Cognitive Biases and Investor Protection Regulation: An Evolutionary Approach. 2006. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1133214
5. Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos. Prospect Theory: An Analysis of Decision under Risk. No. 2, Volume 47. Econometrica. 1979
6. Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos. Loss Aversion in Riskless Choice: A Reference-Dependent Model. 106, Quarterly Journal of Economics. 1991

Authors :

Tags :

Share via :

2 Responses

  1. An interesting approach to clarify some of the fine points in consumer
    behaviour in so far as financial transactions are concerned. My observations /
    comments on some of the points are given below:

    Your Blog
    Reference:

     

    Prospect
    Theory:

     

    a.       Loss
    Aversion: People are
    extremely sensitive about losses and exhibit deep seated loss aversion to even
    small amounts of money. In fact, there is evidence that individuals are more
    sensitive to losses than profits – in fact, people value moderate losses more
    than twice as much equal sized gains (Tversky and Kahneman: 1991). This
    translates into financial decisions that would be at significant variance from
    the theory of expected utility.

    Biases and
    cognitive limitations:

     

    a.       Self-restraint: Consumers often behave in ways that compromise
    long-term well-being for short-term gains. This bias of present consumption
    out-weighing future welfare manifests itself in various forms such as the
    failure to save for retirement. It is also observed that consumers discount
    future benefits/costs in a time-inconsistent manner. For example, if offered
    $100 now and $200 a year from now, a consumer is likely to choose the immediate
    $100. However, when offered $100 five years from now and $200 six years from
    now, a consumer is likely to wait the additional year even though the it is the
    same choice she makes five years from now. This time inconsistent, present
    biased model of discounting is referred to as hyperbolic discounting.

     

     

    My
    Observations:

     

    The analysis given above is based on the behavioural pattern
    of Americans  / Europeans. It does not
    hold good for countries like India. For example, the Gross Domestic Savings
    Rate was 34 % of GDP and the Investment Rate was 32.4 % of GDP. In US, the
    corresponding figures are 3.8 % and 12.5 % respectively.   Anecdotal evidence about the way Indians
    still prefer to use/ reuse/ repair and use of various  items as part of their culture is available.   This also explains the proposition on ‘ Loss
    Aversion’. 

    In US, the popular essay ‘The Market for Lemons’ by the economist George Akerlof  which dealt with the information
    asymmetry  taking the example of why
    Americans do not buy second hand cars. It was also one of the best papers which
    got the author the coveted Nobel Prize also. You have also referred to it under
    the Information overload. But, in Indian context, despite all information
    asymmetry there is a huge second hand market for almost everything. Indians
    save for the future foregoing the pleasures of today. In fact, the term thrift
    in the context of micro-finance is defined as consumption foregone and not as
    excess of income over expenditure.  My
    short point is that your proposition needs to be tested in the Indian context
    which in my opinion is incorrect.

     

    Biases and
    cognitive limitations:

     

    c. Response
    to Framing: People make
    different choices in identical situations because of the way the choices have
    been framed for them. The way in which a problem is described can be
    responsible for upto a 30-40% shift in preferences (Barberis and Thaler: 2003).
    The fact that framing can fundamentally impact consumer choice means that
    investor welfare could be seriously compromised in the absence of
    countervailing regulation.

     

    My observations:

    According to Peter Gray, Psychologist, being human, researchers
    inevitably have wishes and expectations that can affect how they behave and
    what they observe when recording data. The resulting biases are called
    ‘observer-expectancy effects’.  A
    researcher who desires or expects a subject to respond in a particular way may
    unintentionally communicate that expectation and thereby influence the
    subject’s behaviour.  Similarly, subjects
    also have expectations which are called ‘subject-expectancy effects’. Ideally,
    to prevent bias due to subject expectancy and the observer-expectancy, ‘double
    blind experiments’ are the preferred modes .  

    Another issue that needs to be understood is the problems in
    generalising from a sample to a larger population.  So, a good measurement procedure should be
    reliable, sensitive and valid too.  We
    find a number of  studies  in the area of micro-finance have used  Randomised Control Trails (RCT)
    methodology.  In CGAP Blog, considerable
    amount of debate on the use of RCT methodology has been posted.   The problem with the use of RCT is that more
    often they satisfy the first two requirements of research methodology that is
    reliable and sensitive but not the third one, validity. So,  the results 
    generated   reflect the  expectation of the organisation/ agency  engaging the researchers for the job.  In that respect, your observations that the
    investor welfare could be seriously compromised is very polite. But, it is a
    harsh reality in which the consumers are taken for a ride through wrong use of
    questionnaires and methodologies in getting the preferred answers by the
    investigators.

     

    Dr S Santhanam Ph.D (Eco), CAIIB

    General Manager (Retd), NABARD &

    Consultant – Development Finance

    Pune -411006

  2. Thank you Dr. Santhanam for your comment and observations.As you correctly pointed out, there is a dearth of data on how Indian consumers respond in specific situations like the prospect mentioned in the post. This is something that we are hoping will be clearer as we delve deeper into the dynamics of the Indian regulatory system and specific instances of consumer behavior.The post was intended to throw some light on the regulatory import of behavioral economics as a whole and was not meant to be country specific. We will keep your suggestion in mind for our further research.  

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *

Related Posts :